In preparation for a PhD class, I decided to look up what the most influential papers in economics are as of late 2023.1 I wanted to learn what ideas and papers have been most influential. (This is not necessarily the same as “the best” though I do not know how one would objectively measure this.).
Most Influential Economics Papers
The Web of Science makes it easy to pull down the most-cited economics papers. Just use a simple query “wc=(economics)”,
query link. In Oct 2024, this resulted in
I arbitrarily grouped finance and econometrics papers differently to the left. (Actually, I even misclassified some finance and econometrics papers, too. Don’t take this exercise too seriously.) Having said this, I tried to tread lightly when it came to eliminating papers from the WoS list. (it still contains a regional studies paper as well as an ecological economics paper, and even a “futurist” one.) Papers with dead authors have a dagger next to them.
Papers in the “Other” Category
abbrev | authors | year | title | journal | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
24 | LLSV98 | la porta, r; lopez-de-silanes, | 1998 | law and finance | journal of political economy |
48 | SV97 | shleifer, a; vishny, rw | 1997 | a survey of corporate governance | journal of finance |
55 | M03 | melitz, mj | 2003 | the impact of trade on intra-industry reallocation | econometrica |
57 | FS99 | fehr, e; schmidt, km | 1999 | a theory of fairness, competition, and cooperation | quarterly journal of economics |
60 | MRW92 | mankiw, ng; romer, d; weil, dn | 1992 | a contribution to the empirics of economic-growth | quarterly journal of economics |
65 | LLS99 | la porta, r; lopez-de-silanes, | 1999 | corporate ownership around the world | journal of finance |
66 | BBD16 | baker, sr; bloom, n; davis, sj | 2016 | measuring economic policy uncertainty | quarterly journal of economics |
76 | B91 | barro, rj | 1991 | economic-growth in a cross-section of countries | quarterly journal of economics |
77 | GK95 | grossman, gm; krueger, ab | 1995 | economic-growth and the environment | quarterly journal of economics |
81 | ADEH99 | artzner, p; delbaen, f; eber, | 1999 | coherent measures of risk | mathematical finance |
84 | LLSV97 | laporta, r; lopezdesilanes, f; | 1997 | legal determinants of external finance | journal of finance |
105 | CL89 | cohen, wm; levinthal, da | 1989 | innovation and learning: the two faces of r & d | economic journal |
112 | S08 | stern, n | 2008 | the economics of climate change | american economic review |
116 | AH92 | aghion, p; howitt, p | 1992 | a model of growth through creative destruction | econometrica |
120 | KK97 | knack, s; keefer, p | 1997 | does social capital have an economic payoff? a cro | quarterly journal of economics |
121 | M95 | mauro, p | 1995 | corruption and growth | quarterly journal of economics |
124 | GHS05 | gereffi, g; humphrey, j; sturg | 2005 | the governance of global value chains | review of international political economy |
127 | B05 | boschma, ra | 2005 | proximity and innovation: a critical assessment | regional studies |
128 | SV86 | shleifer, a; vishny, rw | 1986 | large shareholders and corporate-control | journal of political economy |
131 | HJ99 | hall, re; jones, ci | 1999 | why do some countries produce so much more output | quarterly journal of economics |
139 | KS85 | katz, ml; shapiro, c | 1985 | network externalities, competition, and compatibil | american economic review |
142 | B73 | blinder, as | 1973 | wage discrimination - reduced form and structural | journal of human resources |
146 | A89 | arthur, wb | 1989 | competing technologies, increasing returns, and lo | economic journal |
147 | AV03 | anderson, je; van wincoop, e | 2003 | gravity with gravitas: a solution to the border pu | american economic review |
152 | PZM05 | pimentel, d; zuniga, r; morris | 2005 | update on the environmental and economic costs ass | ecological economics |
154 | FLO02 | frederick, s; loewenstein, g; | 2002 | time discounting and time preference: a critical r | journal of economic literature |
155 | C83 | calvo, ga | 1983 | staggered prices in a utility-maximizing framework | journal of monetary economics |
156 | G72 | grossman, m | 1972 | concept of health capital and demand for health | journal of political economy |
166 | BHW92 | bikhchandani, s; hirshleifer, | 1992 | a theory of fads, fashion, custom, and cultural-ch | journal of political economy |
168 | ST06 | silva, jmcs; tenreyro, s | 2006 | the log of gravity | review of economics and statistics |
170 | HL02 | holt, ca; laury, sk | 2002 | risk aversion and incentive effects | american economic review |
171 | LLSV99 | la porta, r; lopez-de-silanes, | 1999 | the quality of government | journal of law economics & organization |
179 | LP03 | levinsohn, j; petrin, a | 2003 | estimating production functions using inputs to co | review of economic studies |
181 | HK06 | hyndman, rj; koehler, ab | 2006 | another look at measures of forecast accuracy | international journal of forecasting |
182 | MV77 | meeusen, w; vandenbroeck, j | 1977 | efficiency estimation from cobb-douglas production | international economic review |
183 | N70 | nelson, p | 1970 | information and consumer behavior | journal of political economy |
185 | BS92 | barro, rj; salaimartin, x | 1992 | convergence | journal of political economy |
186 | A90 | andreoni, j | 1990 | impure altruism and donations to public-goods - a | economic journal |
191 | BDM95 | berg, j; dickhaut, j; mccabe, | 1995 | trust, reciprocity, and social-history | games and economic behavior |
195 | LLSV00 | la porta, r; lopez-de-silanes, | 2000 | investor protection and corporate governance | journal of financial economics |
198 | CG09 | croson, r; gneezy, u | 2009 | gender differences in preferences | journal of economic literature |
204 | OP96 | olley, gs; pakes, a | 1996 | the dynamics of productivity in the telecommunicat | econometrica |
206 | CH04 | collier, p; hoeffler, a | 2004 | greed and grievance in civil war | oxford economic papers-new series |
207 | F05 | frederick, s | 2005 | cognitive reflection and decision making | journal of economic perspectives |
211 | R82 | rubinstein, a | 1982 | perfect equilibrium in a bargaining model | econometrica |
217 | DWB02 | de groot, rs; wilson, ma; boum | 2002 | a typology for the classification, description and | ecological economics |
219 | AF09 | adams, rb; ferreira, d | 2009 | women in the boardroom and their impact on governa | journal of financial economics |
220 | L97 | laibson, d | 1997 | golden eggs and hyperbolic discounting | quarterly journal of economics |
224 | B09 | bloom, n | 2009 | the impact of uncertainty shocks | econometrica |
227 | T70 | tullock, g | 1970 | exit, voice and loyalty - responses to decline in | journal of finance |
230 | AR03 | anderson, rc; reeb, dm | 2003 | founding-family ownership and firm performance: ev | journal of finance |
232 | DSSW90 | delong, jb; shleifer, a; summe | 1990 | noise trader risk in financial-markets | journal of political economy |
235 | L97 | levine, r | 1997 | financial development and economic growth: views a | journal of economic literature |
236 | FGNZ94 | fare, r; grosskopf, s; norris, | 1994 | productivity growth, technical progress, and effic | american economic review |
240 | BO00 | bolton, ge; ockenfels, a | 2000 | erc: a theory of equity, reciprocity, and competit | american economic review |
242 | DHG03 | dimasi, ja; hansen, rw; grabow | 2003 | the price of innovation: new estimates of drug dev | journal of health economics |
245 | KM97 | kiyotaki, n; moore, j | 1997 | credit cycles | journal of political economy |
246 | GKSS92 | glaeser, el; kallal, hd; schei | 1992 | growth in cities | journal of political economy |
250 | GSS82 | guth, w; schmittberger, r; sch | 1982 | an experimental-analysis of ultimatum bargaining | journal of economic behavior & organization |
253 | R93 | rabin, m | 1993 | incorporating fairness into game-theory and econom | american economic review |
254 | ALM03 | autor, dh; levy, f; murnane, r | 2003 | the skill content of recent technological change: | quarterly journal of economics |
259 | K74 | krueger, ao | 1974 | political economy of rent-seeking society | american economic review |
260 | BM04 | bertrand, m; mullainathan, s | 2004 | are emily and greg more employable than lakisha an | american economic review |
261 | CEE05 | christiano, lj; eichenbaum, m; | 2005 | nominal rigidities and the dynamic effects of a sh | journal of political economy |
262 | KL93 | king, rg; levine, r | 1993 | finance and growth - schumpeter might be right | quarterly journal of economics |
263 | AG17 | allcott, h; gentzkow, m | 2017 | social media and fake news in the 2016 election | journal of economic perspectives |
265 | SV93 | shleifer, a; vishny, rw | 1993 | corruption | quarterly journal of economics |
267 | FR93 | funtowicz, so; ravetz, jr | 1993 | science for the post-normal age | futures |
270 | P76 | peltzman, s | 1976 | toward a more general theory of regulation | journal of law & economics |
275 | LR92 | levine, r; renelt, d | 1992 | a sensitivity analysis of cross-country growth reg | american economic review |
276 | R28 | ramsey, fp | 1928 | a mathematical theory of saving | economic journal |
282 | B90 | barro, rj | 1990 | government spending in a simple-model of endogenou | journal of political economy |
283 | G54 | gordon, hs | 1954 | the economic theory of a common-property resource: | journal of political economy |
285 | BDL98 | borensztein, e; de gregorio, j | 1998 | how does foreign direct investment affect economic | journal of international economics |
286 | EL97 | easterly, w; levine, r | 1997 | africa’s growth tragedy: policies and ethnic divis | quarterly journal of economics |
288 | RU02 | rockafellar, rt; uryasev, s | 2002 | conditional value-at-risk for general loss distrib | journal of banking & finance |
289 | FR99 | frankel, ja; romer, d | 1999 | does trade cause growth? | american economic review |
294 | MR81 | meltzer, ah; richard, sf | 1981 | a rational theory of the size of government | journal of political economy |
295 | B74 | barro, rj | 1974 | are government bonds net wealth | journal of political economy |
296 | FG00 | fehr, e; gächter, s | 2000 | cooperation and punishment in public goods experim | american economic review |
297 | BRD02 | brazier, j; roberts, j; deveri | 2002 | the estimation of a preference-based measure of he | journal of health economics |
299 | GS89 | gilboa, i; schmeidler, d | 1989 | maxmin expected utility with non-unique prior | journal of mathematical economics |
Future Nobel Prize Winners?
1. Growth and Institutions: Andrei Shleifer et al
Disclaimer: I know Andrei. I am friendly but not friends. I have never been in his circle. He is an amazing scholar.
(The papers Andrei has written with Rob are generally better than the papers he has written without him.) Andrei has further published very influential papers in other areas, too. He has always been academic royalty — in this case, more than deserved. In a sense, he has helped found the modern royal house of Harvard.
2. Panel Econometrics: Stephen Bond (plus)
Disclaimer: I don’t know what I am talking about here. The area is too far from my expertise. I have never met Steve.
Econometrics is difficult for me to judge. Most econometric papers on the list of the top 200 economics papers are variations on unit roots in time-series. Arguably, panel methods have not received as much attention. Bond has two papers on the top-20 list: #6 (Arellano-Bond) and #11 (Blundell-Bond). (I don’t know the relative contributions of Arellano and Blundell to these papers. These two authors may be appropriately included, too.)
4. Others
-
Fairness: Fehr and Schmidt (1999) is very impressive especially because the paper was not from a royal court but a province.
-
Trade: Melitz (2003) is a clear shoe-in. It is also relatively new. The paper’s abstract states that it “adapts Hopenhayn’s (1992a) dynamic industry model to monopolistic competition in a general equilibrium setting.” Maybe this means that Hopenhayn should be a part of this.
-
Economic Growth: There are a large number of papers related to “economic growth” on the top 200 list. They include Mankiew-Romer-Weil (1992); Barro (1991), Grossman-Krueger (1995), Aghion-Howitt (1992), Mauro (1995), Hall-Jones (1999), Rajan-Zingales (1998), and others.
-
Market Microstructure: Pete Kyle, perhaps the smartest guy on the list (and that means a lot!!), has one huge hit conceptual theory paper here, ranked about #100. Of all the non-growth papers in finance, this seems like the most insightful and influential one.
-
Uncertainty: Baker-Bloom-Davis reinvigorated the field by offering novel empirical measures of uncertainty.
Journals With The Highest Frequency of High Impact Papers
Journals | Freq |
---|---|
econometrica | 42 |
journal of political economy | 34 |
american economic review | 30 |
quarterly journal of economics | 27 |
journal of finance | 23 |
journal of financial economics | 19 |
journal of econometrics | 14 |
The remainder was (99%) written a few years ago.
Historical Association
Citation influence is a nice objectively measurable criterion, but it isn’t everything. For example, in my mind, the Nordhaus Nobel Prize is difficult to beat, yet Nordhaus’ highest-impact paper is only about about #400. Similarly, Piketty should probably eventualy win a Nobel Prize, even though his book on inequality is nowhere close to the top here. (Piketty-Saez is ranked around #500.)
Some past Nobel prizes seem to have been given more for “life-time contribution” than for “great ideas.” Others seem to have been given for perceived importance beyond cites (such as Nordhaus). Finally, yet others (especially in the distant past, such as Richard Stone) seem difficult to explain to me.
In 2021, I also spent some time looking at the top-200 papers, not just the plotted top-50 papers. As in the graph based on the top 50 or so papers, the top 200 paper could similarly be grouped into three categories:
- they are econometrics/methods;
- the authors have a Nobel prize, or
- the authors are not in the suitable age category (too young or too dead).
Past Associations of Influence with Nobel Prizes
Not all Nobel Prize winners have had highly influential papers on the top 200 list. In the following, I add the highest cited paper for each Nobel Prize winner in 2022 or so.
Have Top-200 Paper | Have No Top-200 Paper |
---|---|
- Yes: acemoglu (upd #69), akerlof (#16), angrist (#31), arrow (#89), banerjee (#182), becker (#37), coase (#9), diamond (#136), dybvig (#136), engle (#4), fama (#11), hansen (#40), hart (#93), hayek (#63), heckman (#3), holmstrom (#103), johnson (upd #69), kahneman (#1), krugman (#71), kuznets (#76), kydland (#151), lucas (#18), markowitz (#7), merton (#67), miller (#47), modigliani (#47), nash (#84), north (#109), prescott (#151), robinson (upd #69), romer (#23), samuelson (#138), scholes (#6), schultz (#163), sharpe (#33), simon (#38), sims (#64), solow (#25), spence (#46), stigler (#70), stiglitz (#62), thaler (#174), tobin (#105), vickrey (#101), williamson (#85). | - No: bernanke (#307), deaton (#275), debreu (#280), diamond (peter, #405), fogel (>#1000), friedman (#217), frisch (>#1000), goldin(upd >#1000)., haavelmo (>#1000), harsanyi (#517), hicks (>#1000), hurwicz (>#1000), imbens (#294), kantorovich (>#1000), klein (>#1000), koopmans (#977), kremer, (>#1000), leontief (#623), lewis (>#1000), maskin (#710), mcfadden (#272), meade (>#1000), milgrom (#200), mortensen (#576), mundell (#304), myerson (#779), myrdal (>#1000), nordhaus (#415), ohlin (>#1000), ostrom (#356), phelps (#474), pissarides (#576), roth (#957), sargent (>#1000), schelling (>#1000), selten (>#1000), sen (#986), shapley (#231), smith (>#1000), stone (>#1000), tinbergen (>#1000), tirole (#382), wilson (#496). |
More Observations
Among the top 200 papers:
-
The single-most cited work in economics is Kahneman and Tversky’s prospect theory.
-
The most common authors were Shleifer (8), Fama and Vishny (7), Merton and Jensen (5).
-
The youngest entry on the list is the Wooldrige textbook (2010, #35). With the exception of Reinhart-Rogoff (“This time is different”, 2009, #156), all young papers are econometric methods — but, of course, RR is based on a spreadsheet error. the Graham-Harvey-Rajgopal (2005, #151) survey of corporate officers is the youngest other paper (#192).
-
The oldest entry on the list is Hotelling’s competition paper (1929, #79). The next oldest paper is Coase (1937, #10). Talking about staying power!!! These papers have truly stood the test of time.
-
Most of the papers are by American or British authors.
-
Almost exactly one-third of the papers on the top-200 list are on econometric methods, such as panel and unit-root methods. The number of highly-cited papers is greatly overrepresentative relative to the number of econometricians in economics. (They provide useful tools to all of us, in the best sense!) This is also my bad reason for breaking them out.
-
About one-third of the researchers in the broader economics profession are in finance, based on membership in the AEA vs. AFA. This is approximately propotionally reflected in the appearance of finance papers on this list. About one-sixth are asset-pricing papers, just under one-sixth are corporate finance papers.
-
About one-sixth of the paper are in macro- and growth economics.
-
About one-quarter of the papers are (primarily) economic theory. This area distribution seems reflective of the past, more so than the present.
-
Marc Melitz is young but should absolutely eventually win for the Melitz model of trade (already ranked #53 in 2023!).
-
Carhart’s 1997 paper is listed as about #36. However, it is not a good candidate for a Nobel prize, the same way that lots of econometrics papers are not. The paper provides a “specification” control inclusion for the momentum factor.
-
Only 3 of the top 200 papers include a female author: Bertrand-Duflo-Mullainathan (#75^2). Reinhart-Rogoff (#159). Hart-Laury (#171).
- It seems less plausible that women are so few because there was an active coordinated campaign to discriminate against women. Cites are not decided by a small clique (e.g., of men as editors or referees or department chairs). Women are of course as good as economists as men. It seems more likely to me that the dearth of women on this list reflects the historically smaller number of women in economics. Feel free to disagree.
Some critiques about the robustness of findings have been published in
-
Reinhart-Rogoff (see Herndon-Ash-Pollin 2014; but read also the response).
-
For some of the LLSV papers (see Holderness 2016a and Holderness 2016b; no response); and
Final Notes
-
Armen Alchian, Harold Demsetz and Stephen Ross absolutely should have won Nobel prizes when they were alive. How could Richard Stone have won but not Harold Demsetz?
-
Bollerslev [ranked paper #15] should have snuck in with the ARCH Nobel prizes in the past, but it’s probably too late now.
-
I also like Newey-West (#18), but it seems conceptually too derivative to White (#4) even though NW is so widely used. On the other hand, it took 7 years to publish NW after White. Perhaps NW just seems obvious in retrospect.
-
There is a whole universe of papers in ecology, evolution, and economics (e.g., Eric Charnov or Robert Costanza). I am not qualified to judge the relative contributions here, but this literature seems fascinating.
Feel free to drop me a note if I missed something important.
Stupid Dinner Table Trivia
What are the most over- and under-represented beginning letters of the last name of recipients?
Last Name | US Pop | Nobel |
---|---|---|
A | 3.75% | 3 |
B | 8.96% | 3 |
C | 6.38% | 1 |
D | 5.65% | 5 |
E | 2.03% | 1 |
F | 3.63% | 4 |
G | 5.34% | 1 |
H | 5.59% | 9 |
I | 0.76% | 1 |
J | 1.36% | 0 |
K | 5.70% | 8 |
L | 5.24% | 3 |
M | 8.28% | 12 |
N | 2.13% | 3 |
O | 1.63% | 2 |
P | 5.27% | 3 |
Q | 0.26% | 0 |
R | 4.80% | 2 |
S | 10.93% | 16 |
T | 3.88% | 4 |
U | 0.47% | 0 |
V | 2.55% | 1 |
W | 3.46% | 2 |
X | 0.02% | 0 |
Y | 0.65% | 0 |
Z | 1.29% | 0 |
Overrepresented?: S, M, H. F, A.
Underrepresented?: J, Q, U, X, Y, Z. (Well, the Chinese have only more recently entered the profession in large numbers… ;-) )
Footnotes
-
RePeC is not my favorite, because a large part of its scholar rankings is based on authors’ linkage with others. It thus measures “pedigree” as much as it measures “merit.” If anything, the profession should move away from pedigree and more towards merit. (I have benefitted from pedigree, too, though I am only “aristocracy” and not “royalty.”) Moreover, RePeC’s input data is pretty poor, especially with respect to financial economics.
Clarivate’s Web of Science and Google Scholar are both pretty decent sources of citation counts, although they have different normalizers. The rankings are comparable, the raw counts are not. The ISI highly-cited researcher lists are simply terrible, incomprehensible, and irreproducible. Whoeever is in charge of them deserves to be fired.
I deleted Nocedal-Wright (an optimization textbook), the Zurich experimentation toolbox, but left others: The computer movie simulation of Detroit growth from 1970; the econometrics textbooks (angrist-pischke, wolldridge). I removed duplicate entries for pedroni and maddala, and deleted a bookintro (or error?) by Rosewarn. ↩